Additional
articles from SSRN have
been noted by our friend in the Irish Society of
Comparative Law:
Dari-Mattiacci, Giuseppe, Guerriero, Carmine and Huang,
Zhenxing, The Good-Faith Purchaser: Markets, Culture, and the Legal System (June
20, 2012). Amsterdam Law School
Research Paper No. 2012-70; Amsterdam
Center for Law & Economics Working Paper No. 2012-01.
A key legal institution is the
set of rules balancing theft with markets as alternative means to transfer
property rights. Even if all legal systems forbid theft, different societies
provide different ex post solutions to the conflict arising between the
original owner and the good-faith buyer of a stolen good. These rules range from
the full protection of the original owner's property right to the full
protection of the buyer's reliance on contract. In situations in which only
intermediaries can transfer goods by using either theft or markets, society
should condone transfers occurred through theft when innocent buyers value the
good more than original owners and reverse them otherwise. We show that, in the
first case, provided that the difference between the owner's and the buyer's
valuation is not too wide, there are separating equilibria in which moral
intermediaries --- i.e., those for whom theft entails a sufficiently high moral
cost --- signal their proper title by charging higher prices. In the second
case, the market shrinks since moral intermediaries refrain from stealing. In
the most likely case, in which buyers tend to value the good more than original
owners, the extent of protection of the owner increases (decreases) with the
share of moral intermediaries (the quality of the legal system) because of the
lower probability of theft (lower impact of public enforcement). Instrumental
variables estimates based on a cross section of 77 jurisdictions are consistent
with this prediction.
Salomons, Arthur F., Comparative Law and the Quest for Optimal
Rules on the Transfer of Movables for Europe
(June 8, 2012). Amsterdam Law School Research Paper No. 2012-72; Centre for the
Study of European Contract Law Working Paper Series No. 2012-09; European
property Law Journal 2012(3), (forthcoming).
The drafters of Book VIII Draft
Common Frame of Reference (DCFR) have devoted an impressive amount of time and
energy in collecting and publishing comparative data with regard to the
existing property law within all Member States of the European Union, and in
particular with regard to the subject matter of that Book: acquisition and loss
of ownership of movables. This in itself suggests that comparative research
played an important role in the drafting process, and this impression is
enhanced by the abundance of comparative references and notes in the official
Comments to Book VIII. However, the fact that the drafters made an extensive
study of the relevant property law of every European legal system does not
imply per se that the outcome of their comparative research was taken as
guiding in the establishment of the DCFR rules.
In order to gain a better insight into the character of the rules of Book VIII, this contribution seeks to answer the question whether comparative arguments really weighed heavily in the drafting of Book VIII: is the ‘comparative activism’ of its drafters a manifestation of a determination that common or even majority solutions should be the basis of the model rules to be proposed, or did the drafters feel free to propose novel rules even if these were contrary to what applies in most European countries, according to the comparative data they collected and presented themselves? ...
In order to gain a better insight into the character of the rules of Book VIII, this contribution seeks to answer the question whether comparative arguments really weighed heavily in the drafting of Book VIII: is the ‘comparative activism’ of its drafters a manifestation of a determination that common or even majority solutions should be the basis of the model rules to be proposed, or did the drafters feel free to propose novel rules even if these were contrary to what applies in most European countries, according to the comparative data they collected and presented themselves? ...
Schill, Stephan W., Deference in Investment Treaty
Arbitration: Re-Conceptualizing the Standard of Review Through Comparative
Public Law (June 28, 2012). Society of International Economic Law (SIEL), 3rd
Biennial Global Conference.
The standard of review to be
applied by investment treaty tribunals when reviewing host state conduct is a
crucial, but still insufficiently analyzed issue. Although tribunals frequently
make reference to “deference” as the applicable standard, the criteria they
apply to concretize that concept remain uncertain and little predictable. What
is more, the conceptual foundations of granting deference to host states are
opaque. The present paper focuses on these foundations and argues that they are
intrinsically connected to how investment treaty arbitration is qualified as
either a form of commercial arbitration, a means to settle disputes under
public international law, or as an internationalized form of judicial review in
public law disputes. Siding with the latter, the present paper proposes to
conceptualize the standard of review within a separation of powers framework
that fuses domestic and international legal considerations in allocating power
between states and arbitral tribunals. Within this framework, considerations
originating from both international dispute settlement and comparative public
law interact to determine and concretize the standard of review.
Hirsch, Jeffrey M., A Comparative Perspective on Unjust Dismissal Laws (2012). in Global Labor and Employment Law: Reports from Law Offices Worldwide (Samuel Estreicher ed.) 2012.
Hirsch, Jeffrey M., A Comparative Perspective on Unjust Dismissal Laws (2012). in Global Labor and Employment Law: Reports from Law Offices Worldwide (Samuel Estreicher ed.) 2012.
The conclusion drawn from this study challenges the common “American exceptionalism” premise that argues that adopting a just cause rule would place the U.S. in the same company as the rest of the world. It is true that most countries provide employees with more protection against unjust dismissals than the U.S. But even on paper, the protections in many of the surveyed countries are often weaker than the typical American view of just cause protection assumes. Moreover, the actual practice in these countries frequently reveals even less protection, particularly when remedies are taken into account. These considerations make American dismissal law, although certainly weaker, appear less than exceptional.
In addition, the variances in unjust dismissal regimes suggest that many economic studies of employment protection fail to account for the full range of differences that exist among countries. For instance, a study on the effect of employment regulation on a country’s or firms’ economic performance should not rely solely on the laws as they are written because similar looking laws may have substantially different effects due to their available remedies or other operational disparities. Thus, studies should do more to account for these differences or, where appropriate data are unavailable, at least acknowledge that limitation.
No comments:
Post a Comment